Business and Finance

According to game theory, taking the best possible deals is currently not the best long-term strategy

Published

on

Conventional wisdom suggests that it’s best to never leave money on the table when negotiating. However, research in my field suggests that this will be entirely the incorrect approach.

Is increasingly more evidence that a short-term victory at the negotiating table could mean a loss when it comes to overall trust and cooperation. This could put everyone – including the “winner” – at an obstacle.

As a former director, I managed large contracts each as buyers and sellers. Now, as business professor, I examine the relationships of business partners, checking what works in practice. My work confirms what economic theorists and social scientists have been about arguing for years: The best results are achieved when people work together to create long-term value, slightly than fighting for short-term wins.

What game are you playing?

Research dates on the art, science and practice of cooperative approaches back to the Nineteen Forties when mathematician John von Neumann and economist Oskar Morgenstern used mathematical evaluation to model competition and cooperation in living organisms.

Interest in the collaborative approach increased when researchers John Nash, John C. Harsanyi, and Reinhard Selten won the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences in 1994. Their work inspired scientists around the world to delve deeper into the so-called game theory.

Game theory is a science that studies the outcomes of strategic interactions between decision-makers. Using rigorous statistical methods, researchers can model what happens when people determine to cooperate or take an aggressive, power-based approach to negotiation.

Many business leaders learn strategies that deal with using his power and playing for victory – often at the expense of the other side. In game theory this is the so-called zero-sum gameand it is simple to fall into the trap.

Kate Vitasek provides five principles for creating a price creation strategy.

But not every game has a transparent winner or loser. In economics, a game through which either side win is called a non-zero-sum game. In such a situation, people do not argue about whose piece of the pie will probably be larger. They are working to grow the cake for everybody.

The second dimension of game theory is whether people play a single-shot or repeated game. Think of a one-time game like going to a flea market: you most likely won’t see your trading partner again, so if you happen to act like a jerk to them, the risk of repercussions is low.

An interesting fact discovered in the study of repeated games is that when one party uses its power in a negotiation, it causes the other party to want to retaliate.

It was coined by Robert Axelrod of the University of Michigan, a mathematician turned game theorist. tit-for-tat strategy.. His research, perhaps best known for his book “The evolution of cooperation” uses statistics to show that when individuals work together, they perform higher than once they do not.

A case of leaving money on the table

Another Nobel Prize winner, an American economist Oliver Williamsonproposed negotiations advice what most would call a paradigm shift and a few would call heresy.

This advice? Always leave money on the table – especially whenever you keep coming back to the same “game”. Why? According to Williamson, it sends a robust signal of trust and credibility to the negotiation partner when someone consciously decides to cooperate and construct trust.

The opposite approach leads to lack of trust and what Nobel Prize-winning economist Oliver Hart calls “shadowing.” This is retaliatory behavior This happens when a celebration does not achieve the expected result from the contract and feels that the other party is at fault.

Simply put, a non-collaborative approach creates an absence of trust and creates friction, which increases transaction costs and increases inefficiencies.

The million-dollar query is whether collaborative approaches work in practice. From my standpoint as a scientist, the answer is yes. In fields as diverse as Healthcare Down high technologyI see increasingly more real-world evidence supporting game theory insights.

The lessons are easy but profound: Playing together to achieve common interests is higher than playing to solely pursue self-interest.

This article was originally published on : theconversation.com

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

Trending

Exit mobile version